Eurozone Debt Crisis Essay

Greece Euro Debt Crisis Essay

Greece is a country located in Southeast Europe with a population of 10.8 million people. The country is located at the crossroads of Europe, Western Asia, and Africa. Greece's main industries are shipping and tourism and its economy is the largest in the Balkans. In late 2009, the Eurozone began experiencing some economic difficulties. Many European countries suffered the aftermath of the United States’ financial crisis that lasted from 2007 through 2009. Although Greece is the member of the Eurozone that has been in the middle of this ongoing debt crisis since November 2009, Greece has been fighting to stay afloat long before all of this erupted. The effect of the Euro debt crisis made it clear that Greece's excessive budget deficit and mainly its public debt were unsustainable. The crisis caused the interest rates to rise substantially as well as the unemployment rate from the beginning of Euro debt crisis and continuing forward. The gross domestic product declined and the inflation rose as well.
Greece was a starting point of the Euro debt crisis in late 2009 and it rapidly began to spread to other countries with weak financial and macroeconomic conditions. We found this very fascinating and because of that we decided to research further into a country that caused and placed such stress on the European Union. We will address the Euro debt crisis as well as shift the focus on Greece’s role in the crisis. We will discuss the causes, its effects, macroeconomic variables affected, policies adopted in order to solve the crisis, and the effectiveness of the chosen policies.
In the mid 2007, following the bursting of the housing bubble, the United States entered a severe recession. The subprime mortgage crisis and the financial crisis of 2007 in the United States sparked a global recession. This later affected the entire world economy, with greater detriment to some countries than others. United States subprime mortgage loan market crisis transformed into a sovereign debt crisis in the Eurozone. Greece became the first European country affected by this and it later spread into other European countries with weak financial and macroeconomic conditions.
Greece has suffered from an excessive budget deficit long before the Euro debt crisis. Widespread corruption and tax evasion in Greece led to repeated deficits for decades that were covered with debt. A thriving black market economy combined with tax evasion could have cut the country's deficit in half, if it was accounted for. The poor government budget, planning, and competitiveness of the Greek economy further increased the deficits. Even prior to entering the European Union in 2002, it is believed that Greece made a number of questionable currency swaps at a below market exchange rates in order to enter the Eurozone. This led to accusations that Greece misrepresented its financial situation and that it never should have been allowed to become a member of the single currency zone because it did not...

Loading: Checking Spelling

0%

Read more

Greek Withdrawal from the Eurozone Essay

2650 words - 11 pages Months of negotiations on extending Greece's cash-for-reforms deal with the eurozone have collapsed, so the Greek bailout ran out on 30 June and Alexis Tsipras's government failed to make a key debt repayment to the IMF. The European Central Bank (ECB) has said it won't extend emergency funding for the banks and there is a growing risk of Greece leaving the single currency. How in the world did it come to this? Late in 2013 Greece’s public...

Will the Euro Survive? Essay

1495 words - 6 pages "Europe must prevent Greece from becoming an out-and-out catastrophe and make sure that the same fiscal 'remedy' is not applied to other weak economies" -- Franziska Brantner The brutality of the World War II and the anguish of the Cold War enforced nations in Europe to establish the European Union for peace and unity in the region. With ratification of the Maastricht Treaty by members of the European Community in 1993, an economic and...

Greek Economic Crisis

1523 words - 6 pages For the past 5 years, the Greek public has been suffering from an economic crisis. NBCnews.com puts this into a perspective that everyone can understand: Imagine taking a 40% pay cut. Then on top of that you suffer an increase in sales tax to 23%. Add on an increased price on electricity, and a newly formed tax on heating oil. All of that and a $10 price tag on a gallon of gas is enough to ruin a business. That's exactly...

Greek economic crisis

1523 words - 6 pages For the past 5 years, the Greek public has been suffering from an economic crisis. NBCnews.com puts this into a perspective that everyone can understand: Imagine taking a 40% pay cut. Then on top of that you suffer an increase in sales tax to 23%. Add on an increased price on electricity, and a newly formed tax on heating oil. All of that and a $10 price tag on a gallon of gas is enough to ruin a business. That's exactly...

Ecomnomic Security in Greece

1388 words - 6 pages Economic security, nowadays being a part of International security study covers a range of economic issues on both local and international levels. Being a major sector affecting human security (Buzan, 1991, 38), economic security and its components play a significant role in politics and international relations. This paper will discuss one of the components of economic security – financial crisis and specifically the case of Greece. Economic debt...

Will the European Union Survive?

1862 words - 7 pages "Europe must prevent Greece from becoming an out-and-out catastrophe and make sure that the same fiscal 'remedy' is not applied to other weak economies" -- Franziska Brantner “There are three kinds of people: the have's, the have-not's and the have-not-paid-for-what-they-have's” -- Earl Wilson Today, the world faces another economic crisis in the Eurozone. This crisis exists because too many people are consuming more than they are...

The Future of The Euro

2557 words - 10 pages The Future of the EuroThe European Union is the current talk in the world news and for great reason. Many of the nations that make up the union face large deficits and massive debts, while Italy and Greece owe more than they earn. If this situation is not handled correctly this crisis will not only affect the rest of Europe, but will potentially make its way to into the U.S. market. With Europe undergoing an economic depression, their...

Euro Zone Crisis

2661 words - 11 pages Running Head: EURO ZONE CRISIS 1EURO ZONE CRISIS 2Euro Zone CrisisDefining the Euro Zone CrisisThe Euro-zone crisis is a continuous financial crisis that has adversely influenced Euro-zone countries since late 2009. It is a mutual debt, banking and competitiveness...

The Greek Debt Crisis: Causes, Impact and Resolution

3131 words - 13 pages Introduction Greece is a democratic, high income and developed country from the European continent with the 44th highest GDP and the 29nd highest HDI in the world. According to the International Monetary Fund, Greece’s GDP for fiscal year 2012 was USD 266 billion. The service sector accounts the largest chunk of it at 78% that includes the public and tourism sector. The industrial sector contributes to 18% of Greece’s GDP. Greece’s agricultural...

Greece

1074 words - 4 pages On any given day in America we do not have to worry about our economy completely failing or things like the great depression repeating itself. However, not every country is that fortunate and the citizens of these countries have it worse off than most of us care to realize. Greece within the most recent decade has hit a substantial defalcation in their economic sustainability. The major factors that have contributed to this have forced the...

Greece: An Economy in Crisis

2275 words - 9 pages In this paper I will be discussing some causes of the problems with Greece’s economy that has lead it to where it is today. I will also be discussing some austerities being put in place to try to resolve these issues and why they are necessary to help Greece become prosperous again. Greece is currently at a cross roads, their economic practices over the last quarter of a century have brought the country on the brink of being bankrupt. There are...

In the immediate aftermath of the financial meltdown in 2008, the global crisis has made an important shift. By then not the private banking sector, from where the financial crisis originally emerged from, but sovereign states face the risk of default. In order to analyse the multifaceted character of the European sovereign debt crisis, this essay focuses on its systemic causes. Contrary to the argument of popular Northern European politicians and journalists that blame the inability of Southern European states to manage deficit spending, the Eurozone crisis is firstly determined by imbalances in the European Monetary Union, and secondly by imbalances in the global political economy. This paper argues that the vast amount of sovereign debt is therefore not the result of weak Southern European nations, but of inherent structural illnesses that ultimately led to the current crisis. This essay is divided into two sections. The first section examines the problems of the design of the European Monetary Union. In regard to the theory of an ‘Optimum Currency Area’ by Robert Mundell, it analyses the extent to which the EMU has failed to meet the criteria of optimised efficiency. In the absence of an adjustment mechanism for unequal development in Euro member states, the dominance of Germany as leading export nation created severe inequalities. The second section then focuses on the role of the global political economy and imbalances that were created in the ‘era of financialisation’ following the demise of Bretton Woods. The shift to neoliberalism and consequently the liberalisation of finance have led to an increase in speculation with financial assets. The ‘Global Surplus Recycling Mechanism’ – the recycling of surpluses from successful export countries such as Germany and Japan in Wall Street – has massively increased the amount of money available to households in form of debt and thus created speculative bubbles that burst during the financial crisis. The vast debt of Southern European states is therefore determined by systemic failures.

Beginning with an analysis of the systemic issues in the European Monetary Union, the design of the EMU differs significantly from Robert Mundell’s and Ronald McKinnon’s criteria of an ‘Optimum Currency Area’ (Manolopoulos, 2011). The unequal development in Eurozone member countries requires an adjustment mechanism that smoothens out imbalances between surplus- and deficit nations (Grahl, 2011). This mechanism would replace the ‘usual’ adjustment in form of currency devaluation in deficit countries against currencies in surplus countries. Because a fixed exchange rate automatically fixes competition between economic sectors of member-states (Conquest & Bruges Group, 2011), the following five criteria need to be ensured in order to adjust imbalances (Mundell, 1961).

Firstly a currency union needs to have a flexible labour market. Labour from deficit countries cannot be restricted to move to areas with more successful industries. This factor prevents unemployment to rise in deficit areas and skill shortages to occur in surplus countries with faster growing economies. Within the European Union however, labour mobility was relatively low. According to a report by the European Central Bank, “in 2000, only 0.1% of the total EU-15 population (or 225,000 people) changed official residence between two member countries“ (Heinz & Ward-Warmedinge, 2006). Furthermore most of labour mobility was due to an influx of workers from Eastern Europe rather than from Southern European countries, which are now part of the Eurozone. In contrast, labour migration between US counties was 5.9 % of its total population in 2000 (Heinz & Ward-Warmedinge, 2006).

The second mechanism for an optimum currency union is the establishment of fiscal transfers to counteract asymmetric imbalances (Manolopoulos, 2011). This includes international transfers to balance out surpluses and deficits of successful and less successful regions by a strong central government with a federal taxation system. In the EU however, only 1.24 % of its total GDP has been used for fiscal transfers (Macdougall, 1992). In the dollar zone on the contrary, the central government compensated about 40% of falls in any state’s GDP with fiscal transfers (Callinicos, 2001).

Thirdly, Mundell emphasises the importance of flexible capital and product markets (Manolopoulos, 2011). Wages and prices have to be flexible and responsive to competitive market forces. In the European Union however, especially German wages have been politically repressed for the benefit of German business with the Agenda 2010. There was an artificial redistribution from the German and European citizenry to the German business class. Most of Germany’s ‘export miracle’ was not due to intensive increases in productivity rates, but the result of extensive wage (and demand) repression. The high competitiveness of German unit labour costs compared with Spain, Italy or Greece thus created another imbalance in the European Monetary Union (Conquest & Bruges Group, 2011). Within the Eurozone however, the adjustment of labour costs is an important factor for outbalancing any productivity rise in other nations. Germany, which has been the most successful surplus-generating country of the EU anyhow thus applied a mercantilist policy and restored its own ‘productivity’ through wage repression.

Another important factor is that most of the members have shared business cycles to prevent asymmetric shocks and imbalances (Manolopoulos, 2011). This includes similar inflation rates, which are furthermore closely connected to the degree of integration of member countries. The problem in the EMU is that the inflation policies of the European Central Bank are largely influenced by the imperative of the former German Bundesbank. With the conditions of the Growth and Stability Pact many member states adopted strategies to adapt to the proposed inflation rates at the expense of high unemployment rates (Baimbridge, Burkit, & Whyman, 1998).

Finally, the degree of diversification of the member economies is positively correlated to the optimisation of currency union (Manolopoulos, 2011). Due to the fact that during recessions a region that relies on a few economic sectors can be affected more severely, this criterion needs to be ensured. Though all industrialised member states of the European Union fulfil this criterion, Greece’s economy was relatively undiversified.

The EMU is thus far from Mundell’s concept of an optimum currency union. With low labour mobility, the lack of fiscal transfers, artificial repression of German unit labour costs, inflation policies that serve the interest of surplus countries and a low degree of diversification of the Greek economy, the adoption of a single currency in the 1991 Maastricht Treaty seemed to be a fairly irrational decision. Because most of Germany’s surplus is generated by the export to other EMU member countries, those countries consequently have to run a deficit in the zero-sum-game of balance sheets. According to Eurostat, the intra-EU27 trade balance of Germany made up a surplus of 61912 euro in 2010[1]. Spain and Greece on the other hand run deficits of roughly -11000 and -15000 euro in the same year. Because the normal adjustment mechanism of exchange rate devaluation however was not possible anymore, and because the criteria of the optimum currency area have not been implemented, the European Monetary Union itself entails significant systemic issues that determined the Eurozone crisis.

In addition, the role and policy preferences of Germany during the crisis have exacerbated its severity. The popular press and politicians in Germany have not recognised the systemic failures of the EMU and blame Southern European states for their inability to deal with deficits on the contrary. It is however logically impossible for all member states of the European Union to adopt the same policy preferences as Germany – if every country in the Eurozone relied on mercantilist imperatives, the system could not work. The Eurozone did not base on fair multilateralism between its members, but on a national hegemonic project of Germany (and France). Nationalism in the EU is persistent and still dominates decision-making processes. The role of Germany as an export country and the simultaneous lack of an adjustment mechanism have created significant imbalances within the Eurozone that ultimately determined the current crisis.

Having analysed the systemic issues in the construction of the Eurozone and the consequences of Germany as an export country, the solution of austerity does not seem to be a sustainable long-term orientation for Southern European countries such as Greece. This is the case firstly because the crisis is not primarily caused by weaknesses of corruption in Southern countries and does thus not require a mechanism to remove those supposed origins, and secondly because the negative effects of austerity – the loss of jobs and demand – seem to exacerbate the crisis rather than to resolve it: “with austerity, the automatic stabilizers in the economy that cushion an economic downturn are over-ridden and growth falls” (Carlin, 2011). As recognised by the World Economic Forum in Davos, the German-Franco axis should thus rethink those measurements and focus on long-term growth stabilisers rather than austerity. The bailout agreements signed by Greece however entail the conditionality of those policies.

Next to the imbalances created by the construction of the European Monetary Union and the role of Germany as mercantilist country there are further imbalances in the global political economy that determined the sovereign debt crisis in Europe. In the demise of the Bretton Woods system and the age of neoliberalism that emerged after, the increasing amount of global wealth that was used in the financial sector created speculation and ultimately determined the financial crisis of 2007-2009. Most of the surpluses of successful countries such as Germany and Japan were channelled into Wall Street and then bundled to cheap credit. This ‘Global Surplus Recycling Mechanism’ (Varoufakis, 2011) in fact actively looked for vast amounts of debtors. This paper therefore argues that the imbalances created in the ‘age of financialisation’ present the second systemic illness that determined the Eurozone crisis.

In the early 1970s, the global political economy experienced a major downturn due to global overproduction in relation to global demand (Brenner, 2002). The fixed exchange rate system of the Bretton Woods era began to unravel as a result of massive US debt and speculative attacks on the US-dollar. Many governments that had interlocked their financial positions with the dollar lost trust in the pillars of Bretton Woods: “by the end of the 1960s many governments began to worry that their own positions (…) were being undermined. By early 1971, (US) liabilities exceeded $70 billion, while the US government possessed only $12 billion of gold with which to back them up” (Varoufakis, 2011). After President Nixon’s closure of the gold window, the US government had to attract global surpluses to finance their balance of payment deficit (Schwartz, 2010). This ‘Global Surplus Recycling Mechanism’ thus recycled capital from the world (most notably Germany, Japan and China from 2003 onwards) in Wall Street.

These asymmetric inflows of surpluses furthermore massively increased liquidity and the availability of credit. With the era of neoliberalism and the liberalisation of finance those surpluses were then channelled into cheap credits and new financial instruments. For example, a vast amount of credit created real estate bubbles in Ireland (Finn, 2011) and Spain. Those bubbles made up an artificial stimulus by the neoliberal regime to boost employment. Debt therefore was generated in the private sector: it was thus not public debt that determined the crisis for those countries, but private debt as the result of financialisation. According to Martin Wolf, “Estonia, Ireland and Spain had vastly better public debt positions than Germany” (Wolf, 2011).

The era of financialisation – the value extension of financial means in relation to production, the increasing scope of financial institutions in regard to financial liberalisation, and the increasing range of financial instruments – determined the financial crisis and consequently the European sovereign debt crisis. The colletaralised debt obligations, repacked in the process of ‘Global Surplus Recycling’, channelled to US households and sold to financial institutions and actors all over the world, represent an era of free-market capitalism. Sovereign actors, which then bailed out private banks, make up the final stage of debtors in the recent crisis. The contagion of debt thus spread from households to banks to governments.

Moreover some politicians have accused financial markets themselves of worsening the crisis by panic and speculation about sovereign debt. The EU parliament tried to decrease speculation with sovereign debt through banning the purchase of credit default swaps (CDS) without already holding government bonds. According to a publication of the European Parliament in November 2011, “this is one of the key regulations pushed through by the Commission to tackle the financial crisis. Both short selling and CDS trading are accused of having fuelled the market volatility, with CDS trades moreover having been widely blamed for potentially aggravating Greece’s troubles” (European Parliament, 2011).

The problem with such accusations is they do not focus on the broader picture. It is indeed true that speculation with sovereign debt has worsened the situation in Greece to a certain extent. However, the actual origin is the contagion of debt in the whole economic system. One has to ask why such speculation occurs – and narrowing the answer to that question to the mere greed of some speculating actors is wrong. It is the system that lies behind such speculation, the construction of the Eurozone, and the whole global political economy.

In conclusion, this paper argues that contrary to popular press and politicians that blame Southern European states for weakness and corruption, the origins of the current Eurozone crisis are to be found in two broader systemic issues: firstly the construction of the European Monetary Union, and secondly the global political economy and the age of financialisation. This paper shows that the adoption of the euro was built on unsustainable pillars and far from the theoretical principle of Mundell’s optimum currency area: labour mobility was low in the EU; there were neither fiscal transfers from surplus to deficit countries, nor a federal taxation system; wages have not been subject to EU-wide market forces, but have been artificially repressed by Germany; and inflation policies have favoured the interest of the strongest members. Further imbalances were created by Germany as mercantilist country and surplus generator at the expense of other EU members. Austerity thus does not seem to be the right policy solution, as it oppresses demand and thus creates more sovereign debt. Furthermore, this paper argues that the second systemic issue lies in the construction of the global political economy and the imbalances created in the era of neoliberalism. The contagion of debt that spreads through the Global Surplus Recycling Mechanism – from surplus countries to households, to banks, to sovereign states – has afflicted the whole system. The massive amount of debt in Southern European countries is thus not determined by weakness, corruption, and inabilities to deal with public deficits, but by systemic failures and illnesses. Therefore, to prevent such crisis from emerging it is the system itself that needs to be changed.

Bibliography

Baimbridge, M., Burkit, B., & Whyman, P. (1998). Is Europe Ready for EMU? Theory, Evidence and Consequences. Abgerufen am 2012. 02 23 von The Bruges Group: http://www.brugesgroup.com/mediacentre/index.liv e?article=102

Brenner, R. (2002). The boom and the bubble: the U.S. in the world economy. New York: Verso.

Callinicos, A. (2001). The Contradictions of European Monetary Union. In W. Bonefeld, The Politics of Europe : Monetary Union and Class. Basingstoke: Palgrave.

Carlin, W. (2011). 10 Questions on the crisis in the Eurozone. Abgerufen am 2012. 02 21 von University College London European Institute Commentary: http://www.ucl.ac.uk/european-institute/comment_analysis/eurozone

Conquest, R., & Bruges Group. (2011). German economic policy and the Euro, 1999-2010. London: Bruges Group.

European Parliament. (15. Nov 2011). European Parliament News Publications. Abgerufen am 2012. Feb 26 von http://www.europarl.europa.eu/news/en/pressroom/content/20111115IPR31525/html/Parliament-seals-ban-on-sovereign-debt-speculation-and-short-selling-limitations

Finn, D. (2011). Ireland on the Turn? Political and Economic Consequences of the Crash. Vol 67 .

Grahl, J. (2011). Crisis in the Eurozone’. Soundings, Vol.47, No. 47 , S. 143 – 158.

Heinz, F. F., & Ward-Warmedinge, M. (Oct 2006). Cross-border Labour Mobility within an enlarged EU. Occasional Paper Series, No. 52 .

Kouvelakis, S. (2011). Greek Cauldron. New Left Review, Vol. 72 .

Lapavitsas, C., & Kaltenbrunner, A. (2010). The Eurozone between Austerity andDefault. Research on Money and Finance occasional papers, No. 2 .

Macdougall, D. (May 1992). Economic and Monetary Union and the European Community Budget. National Institute Economic Review , 64 – 68.

Manolopoulos, J. (2011). Greece’s’ Odious’ Debt: The Looting of the Hellenic Republic by the Euro, the Political Elite and the Investment Community. Anthem Press.

Mundell, R. A. (Sep 1961). A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas. The American Economic Review, Vol. 51, No. 4 , 657-665.

Schwartz, H. M. (2010). States versus Markets – The Emergence of a Global Economy. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmilian.

Varoufakis, Y. (2011). The Global Minotaur: America, the True Orgins of the Financial Crisis and the Future of the World Economy. London: Zed.

Wolf, M. (2011). Merkozy failed to save the eurozone. Financial Times. 06. Dec 2011 online retrieved from ft.com: http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/396ff020-1ffd-11e1-8662-00144feabdc0.html#axzz1fwLi3F1I


[1] Retrieved from http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal/external_trade/data/main_tables

Written by: Annemarie Detlef
Written at: Hult International Business School
Written for: Andrew Wright
Date written: February 2012 

Comments

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *